September 2022

Sun Mon Tue Wed Thu Fri Sat
        1 2 3
4 5 6 7 8 9 10
11 12 13 14 15 16 17
18 19 20 21 22 23 24
25 26 27 28 29 30  
Blog powered by Typepad

« Ezra Klein Mistakes the Arsonist for a Firefighter | Main | The Chicago Plan Revisited »

Comments

Feed You can follow this conversation by subscribing to the comment feed for this post.

I'm not an economist, but I can give my own take from my discipline (computational physics):

The belief that a scientist doesn't need to know the history of his discipline is completely mistaken. Even in the hard sciences, "laws" are theories constructed by someone to try to explain observations. Mathematical formulas are not "objective," they exist because some researcher constructed an argument for why this particular abstract formula should mode that particular real-world phenomenon. When doing research in any theoretical framework, you need know where that theory came from, what it superseded, what concerns it addresses, and so on.

This sort of thinking is necessary so that theories are not treated as external facts. In my opinion, when a theory is merely presented in an abstract way, without any historical context, it lends it an additional air of authority it doesn't deserve to have. Knowing the history keeps in mind that, like everything else we do, theories are the work of human minds, and as such may be flawed, may be superseded, and may be critiqued.

It is additionally helpful to understand how the person who formulated a theory tended to think about the subject in general, to know whether that general paradigm is useful or not, or to be more aware of its limitations.

Further, not knowing the history of the discipline means not knowing the debates that happened in it and may in fact still be ongoing.

Much of achieving deep & sound scientific understanding in economics involves getting the problem right, and a good deal of that involves achieiven a sound mapping out all of the conceptual space where you vs the explanatory problem wrong.

As Hayek & Popper put it, our negative knowledge of what is not the case is as important as as any of our positive knowledge.

Economics is the most complex and multifaceted of all the sciences.

It takes a massive assembly o reminders to keep track of all of the dimensions of the conceptual space involved, to understand that space you need to know what are tempting blind alleys -- and why they are blind alley.

Getting clear on what has gone wrong is important in gainin understanding of what has gone right in economics.

Contained in the lifes works of great economists are massive efforts to map out the conceptual space of economic understanding -- both negative knowledge of tempting but flawed efforts and positive knowledge of formal achievements, and the limitations and strengths of their many possible uses.

Economics is massively complex and hard -- the assemble of reminders required to be truly excellent is mind boggling.

Nowhere are these reminders assembled as deep and thought generating form as in he massive efforts of the great economists across life times.

I'll add one, specifically in economics--

The idiotic ideas of Karl Marx keep coming back from the grave over and over again. The people best-equipped to explain why his ideas are idiotic are economists. But if you don't know your history, you probably don't know them, because they have zero currency in modern economic thought. Yet, I think if economists inspire to inform the public, it is absolutely necessary to know some Marx and the classic responses of economics to his lunacy.

What we think of as "theory" is a summary statement whose meaning is fleshed out by examples, qualifications, and applications. If you read original sources on "the classical theory of value," it comes out way better than in the textbook comparison with marginalism. Mill's famous error to the effect that we were all done with value theory looks more reasonable in the context of his total approach to the topic as opposed to any summary statement. If we stop reading the old masters, we loose all that texture, and lots of the analysis is in the texture. If modern economies are complex in some sense, then we lose a lot when we lose that texture.

Modern history is written to justify the dominant position in any subject and create a bulwark against attacks on that position. As Butterfield wrote, it is official history.

Everyone knows some history, but it is mostly official history. Those who care about the truth always need revisionist history.

@Roger: I was surprised, on reading Smith, to not find the kind of "labor theory of value" that I was expecting. Of course, there was a labor theory of value, but he didn't try to abstract everything into measurable units of unskilled labor. The way he talks about value is significantly "fuzzier" than later attempts to formulate an explicit labor theory.

Economics, especially macro, makes better sense when it is taught as history. The historical framework provides the structure to help understand the development of theory and applications over time. With Macro, students may get frustrated not knowing what is the "right" theory. Instead, when a subject is taught as an unfolding of history, debates and advances build on each other. A good example of this is Mark Skousen's "The Structure of Production."

What Greg said about getting the problem right.

When a field seems to be struggling, it might help to consider what is most required: (1) new, more or better data to test theories (and policies); (2) new or better theories to test; (3) critical examination of the framework assumptions of the paradigm or the program; or (4) critical comparison of the framework assumptions of rival programs.

With hindsight and the belated publication of Popper's thoughts on metaphysical research programs it looks as though Kuhn and Lakatos led the field of philosophy and methodology in economics astray because they explicitly blocked criticism of the framework assumptions.

Whe a field is making good progress it can get along with the focus on (1) and (2) but when things foul up at the framework level, then some attention to (3) and (4) may help.

On the topic of macro, last week I gave myself bad dreams by scanning several books by Roger Backhouse on macro, he is one of the most rabid Keynesians in the world. In contrast it was a joy to read Thomas Mayer "Truth versus Precision in Economics" which must be a classic exposure of the way theorists have lost touch with the world outside the window. "The principle of the strongest link". Beautiful!

If econ theory (or physics, for that matter) were like the solution to a jigsaw puzzle, then once the puzzle is solved it's solved, and the history of how it was solved, while perhaps interesting, must mean nothing to the correctness of the solution itself. I doubt that that is quite the situation even in physics, much less in econ, though practitioners of the currently dominant paradigm obviously have an incentive to think that it is.

McKinney: "Modern history is written to justify the dominant position in any subject and create a bulwark against attacks on that position."

--A salient observation, in my opinion. Of course, for those who are willing, there are dissenting texts to be sought out and studied, which provide a more diverse perspective and perhaps put one in a better position to apply the lessons of the past to our own time. Now, a standard econ textbook isn't a history per se, but it presents the dominant view of the OUTCOME of the intellectual history. Many voices of the past would have disagreed with this outcome in whole or in part, and they might have been right (though swept aside), or at least partially right, or they may have framed or addressed some issues in ways that we would find useful now.

I suggest that the heart of theoretical advances in disciplines such as econ and physics lies in modeling--not necessarily math modeling but rather generating theoretical constructs that sufficiently resemble or capture features of the world such that by studying them we also learn about what we can expect from the world. In the past, many talented people developed many models, of which many were abandoned, others downplayed, and some elevated to centrality in the dominant paradigm. Many of the abandoned or downplayed models might well, in light of future thought and experience, turn out to be useful, either as-is or with additional development. So: the original writings may be a veritable treasure trove, for those willing to sift through them.

That would be my start on an answer--my prospectus to an answer--to Pete's question, a wonderful question that deserves attention.

Your style is really unique compared to other people I have
read stuff from. I appreciate you for posting when you have the opportunity, Guess I'll just bookmark this site.

Allan, thanks but that insight came from the great British historian Butterfield.

Even though modern economics ignores history, textbooks often throw in some history with sidebars on famous economists whom the author thinks provided the foundation for his approach to economics.

I think the whole point of ignoring history and the high degree of selectivity in picking famous economists to highlight in texts is to keep students from questioning the assumptions.

"The belief that a scientist doesn't need to know the history of his discipline is completely mistaken."

This is correct. Many people can get by in a discipline working on very limited technical issue with little knowledge of the history of the field, but the great ones know that history, and it will make anyone better.

I have been reading a lot of early twentieth century economics recently. My most interesting discovery is that much of the discussion in Schumpeter's 1908 book ("The Nature and Essence of Economic Theory" aka "Das Wesen")is right on target in today's debates about the role of psychology in economics.

The review of this book by Friedrich Wieser shows what a balancing act Austrians had to engage in to preserve the mentalistic aspects of action against the total incorporation of psychology into economic theory.

Schumpeter was a very brilliant instrumentalist who, unfortunately however, tried to throw out all of mentalistic "embellishments" from *static* economic theory with the psychological bathwater. Much of what he wrote seems just like the views of the contemporary neoclassical critics of behavioral economics, Gul and Pesendorfer.

Mario, interesting comment about Schumpeter. Did you see the post at Circle Bastiat with Rothbard's take on him? Here's an excerpt:

"To admire Schumpeter, as many economists have done, for his alleged realistic insight into economic history in seeing technological innovation as the source of development and the business cycle, is to miss the point entirely. For this conclusion is not an empirical insight on Schumpeter’s part; it is logically the only way that he can escape from the Walrasian (or neo-Walrasian) box of his own making; it is the only way for any economic change to take place in his system."

I think we need to make a distinction between economics and political economy. I explained differences in this short article [http://laissezfaire.ufm.edu/index.php?title=Laissezfaire33_7.pdf]

What's up, yup this piece of writing is really nice and I have learned lot of things from it about blogging. thanks.

Great post, it was knowledgeable. Thanx for sharing with us.

The comments to this entry are closed.

Our Books