Steven Horwitz
My reading group is tackling the "Principles and Expediency" chapter of Hayek's Law, Legislation, and Liberty today. I always forget how terrific this chapter is and it's full of quotable stuff and some of Hayek's best work on the importance of ideas and the role of ideologies. But I also found this little digression about the main message of The Road to Serfdom that is of interest, especially given Greg Ransom's tireless (and laudable) efforts to correct the misreadings that are out there. Hayek wrote in 1973 (p. 58, my emphasis):
What I meant to argue in The Road to Serfdom was certainly not that whenever we depart, however slightly, from what I regard as the principles of a free society, we shall ineluctably be driven to go the whole way to a totalitarian system. It was rather what in more homely language is expressed when we say: "If you do not mend your principles you will go to the devil." That this has often been misunderstood to describe a necessary process over which we have no power once we have embarked on it, is merely an indication of how little the importance of principles for the determination of policy is understood, and particularly how completely overlooked is the fundamental fact that by our political actions we unintentionally produce the acceptance of principles which will make further action necessary.
It would seem to me that this is a clear statement that the "inevitability hypothesis" reading of RTS is a bunch of nonsense. In fact, one might argue that the Western world did, by the 1980s, "mend its principles" at least enough to avoid going to the devil completely. Of course whether that "mending" job was strong enough to withstand a real challenge seems dubious as we quickly abandoned any recollection of those principles we might have had in the face of an apparent crisis in 2008, and one that resulted from the political choices that were evidence that we had not sufficiently mended them - namely the attempt to expand access to housing via the Fed and policy intervention.
It sounds like Hayek was anticipating the sort of theory that Prof. Ikeda laid out in his "Dynamics of the Mixed Economy." I think the punchline is basically that over time the degree of state intervention can swing to and fro, based on changes in things like ideology, economic environment, and so forth.
Posted by: J Oxman | October 21, 2011 at 11:15 AM
Inevitability, no. But one should not underestimate the self-perpetuating and reinforcing feedback associated with collectivist policies. Social Security is a disaster, but what now? Some of the more radical libertarians would cut it off cold, but most of us accept that people who were forced to pay in and now depend on it must be taken care of. Government intervention in money and in the housing market gave us the financial bust and recession, but if the problems are successfully (though falsely) blamed on the market, they become the impetus for yet more intervention. The point is not merely that "if you don't mend your principles you will go to the devil," but that the downhill slide becomes harder to reverse, the farther it goes.
Posted by: Allan Walstad | October 21, 2011 at 01:30 PM
Good post and I think it complements Pete's prior post on Coase. Both Hayek and Coase have been misrepresented in the literature.
I am always amazed how people can misread plain and simple texts. Of course, many rely on second-hand accounts rather than reading original texts.
Posted by: Jerry O'Driscoll | October 21, 2011 at 06:16 PM
That quote should settle that debate. There is another problematic quote in the book "Possibly nothing has done so much harm to the liberal cause as the wooden insistence of some liberals on some rough rules of thumb, above all the principle of laissez faire". Chapter 1 p 17 of the Uni of Chicago 22nd impression in 1975).
Can someone explain what principles of laissez faire Hayek found objectionable?
Posted by: Rafe Champion | October 22, 2011 at 01:30 AM
Rafe,
I think what he meant there was that if "laissez-faire" means that we should never consider piecemeal adjustment of the rules so that improved rules could generate better unintended orders, sticking to "laissez-faire" was a mistake. For Hayek, liberals should be willing to make those piecemeal adjustments (e.g. clarifying the status of intellectual property in our own time) in order to remedy avoidable problems.
Posted by: Steve Horwitz | October 22, 2011 at 11:49 AM
I wonder what might explain some, if not all, of the reasons why the inevitability interpretation has become so well-accepted. Set aside opportunism and dogmatic adherence to a political belief in interventionism, even if these might be most of the explanation, put together. Is there a reason why the zeitgeist would blind people to the other interpretation of Hayek (the interpretation that seems plain and obvious to you and also to me)?
One possibility that comes to mind is the theory of history that what did in fact happen was the only possible course of events that could possibly have been. My sense is that Hayek, among others, wrote about this mistaken belief.
Posted by: Harry David | October 22, 2011 at 05:16 PM
Samuelson's textbook bears some blame Harry.
Posted by: Steve Horwitz | October 22, 2011 at 06:56 PM
Is the welfare state stable, or is it not? Is it more complicated than that? Hayek says no, right?
Posted by: Ted Burczak | October 22, 2011 at 08:13 PM
Thanks David, that must be kind of position that would leave the trade unions and the indusrialists to fight it out without any help from the state to control aggressive violence or protect property rights, or the rights of workers to cross a picket line. That is certainly a disastrous and wooden-headed position but who promoted it? The trade unions?
Harry, the standard critique of historical determinism is/are Popper's arguments in The Poverty of Historicism and The Open Society and its Enemies. Helpfully condensed:)
http://www.the-rathouse.com/2008/Poverty-of-Historicism.html
The case for intervention by piecemeal engineering has been muddled by von Mises' attacks on social egineering without noting that Popper's take on engineering was identical with Mises' own practice. The Poverty remains a little noticed treasure trove of hints including the advice to pursue institutional analysis (near the end) and to take a critical/experimental attitude to public and private policies and actions so we learn something.
Posted by: Rafe Champion | October 22, 2011 at 10:07 PM
If I remember correctly, in the edition of RTS I bought in the mid-90's, Hayek explicitly refutes the oft-repeated "inevitability" claim; repeated the old adage, "nothing is inevitable except thinking makes it so."
Posted by: Adam Simpson | October 23, 2011 at 02:39 AM
This statement of Hayek's is what inspired my work with Glen Whitman in our "The Camel Nose is in the Tent: Rules, Theories and Slippery Slopes" in the UCLA Law Review. It is also the essence of Herbert Spencer's argument in his essay "The Coming Slavery." Here he says the key question for the "practical" man of affairs (the politician) is: What kind of society am I tending to produce? Specific policies imply, in a context of argument, certain principles. The principles go on the have a life of their own.
This is why I think the issue-by-issue approach to policy, even when practiced by free-market economists, is low-brow. The main consequences of a policy are usually not what we think of in terms of efficiency, etc but rather the precedential significance of those policies.
We are all, including Hayek, indebted to David Hume for this insight.
Posted by: Mario Rizzo | October 23, 2011 at 03:43 PM
In LLL (1973), Hayek quoted Menger on the pragmatism that leads to socialism. He described liberalism as the system of principles.
I'm not sure how all that squares with the idea of piecemeal adjustments. Particularly so if one takes into account public choice.
Posted by: Jerry O'Driscoll | October 23, 2011 at 04:53 PM
The leftist grad students at Harvard in the 1930s and 1940s absolutely hated Hayek - e.g. Samuelson & Solow -- there's got to be a story there.
Sameulson took several opportunities to slander Hayek on false grounds.
Solow is still trashing Hayek -- based his hate for Hayek's Prices and Production as a student forced to read the book 65 years ago, and based on utterly bogus perceptions of the contents of Hayek's TRtoS, although Solow says he's never read any Hayek except P&P.
Hayek says he was despised by exonomists in many departments -- and these were two of them who led the blanket party ....
Posted by: Greg Ransom | October 23, 2011 at 08:19 PM
Jerry what do you see as the alternative to piecemeal adjustments, bearing in mind that it is not a matter of size or scope as much as alertness to undesirable consequences and learning from experience?
Commonsense one might say, but too many people have not learned the real lessons of dirigism.
Posted by: Rafe Champion | October 24, 2011 at 12:19 AM
Rafe,
I just think there is a tension between Hayek of the RTS and later Hayek on principle vs. expediency. Take a look at the US tax code as an outcome to "piecemeal adjustment." Does anyone think that anyhting less than radical reform is the answer?
Posted by: Jerry O'Driscoll | October 24, 2011 at 11:22 AM
The later Hayek recommends "radical reform" at some times if "piecemeal adjustment" has taken things off track, or in order to set up better systems which privilege principle over expedience, e.g. radical constitutional reform of the sort undertaken in ancient Athenians or by the Americans, or recommended by Hayek's "invention" of a different system of elections and representation, one based on age cohorts.
Posted by: Greg Ransom | October 24, 2011 at 11:35 AM
Hayek distinquishes between small adjustments of the law to advance their application coherence and coordination, etc. and all sorts of "piecemeal" expediencies of the legislature to buy advantages, pursue particular ends, and to advance particular interests.
Distinctions between different kinds of "adjustment" are important here, adjustments to make the principles more general and coherent vs. adjustment to steamroll over principles to achieve particular plans and temporary ends for particular interests.
Posted by: Greg Ransom | October 24, 2011 at 11:40 AM
I agree with O'Driscoll. There are things that are so crooked that cannot be made straight. Most things that come out of politics are such: legislation, tax codes, addiction to parasitism, macroeconomic disequilibria.
In small doses it looks like that political problems can be counteracted, then a threshold is hit and a positive feedback ensures that things can't go straight unless a miracle occurs. There is no piecemeal solution for Argentina, Greece, and probably Italy: only a moral and intellectual miracle che change things. Anything short of total collapse would leave the underlying problems unscathed.
Let's consider Mancur Olson's theory of the decline of nations. When the political structure becomes corrupt to the core because of interest politics, a decline is almost impossible to avoid in the long-run, except in case of radical political shocks, which I wouldn't want to experience.
There is no happy end when entrepreneurial efforts instead of being directed toward wealth production are deviated toward rent seeking. It is as hard as imagining a functional financial system under interventionist financial policies such as ours.
Posted by: Pietro M. | October 24, 2011 at 05:11 PM
Thanks Jerry, I think we are on the same track, bearing in mind Greg's distinction between different kinds of adjustments.
A great precedent for the kind of reform that I think we would both like to see was Erhard's "bonfire of regulations" in Germany.
I don't want to adocate bombing Brussells but it is tempting (for the greater good!).
Posted by: Rafe Champion | October 25, 2011 at 02:54 AM
Greg,
At a more practical level, I interpret this as allowing for the legislative correction of situations where order distorting decisions (and other sources of law) have made jurisprudence. Would you agree with that formulation?
Posted by: Mathieu Bédard | October 27, 2011 at 05:00 AM
I realize this is stale, but already in the ORIGINAL INTRODUCTION to RTF Hayek writes: "Nor am I arguing that these developments are inevitable. If they were, there would be no point in writing this."
Posted by: sandy ikeda | October 29, 2011 at 03:04 PM