Richard Rorty reviewed Macr Hauser's Moral Minds: How Nature Designed Our Universal Sense of Right and Wrong in the Sunday August 27th Book Review section of the New York Times. Rorty shows great respect for brain research, but he ultimately questions the implications for practical affairs. As he puts it:
Knowing more details about how the diodes in your computer are laid out may, in some cases, help you decide what software to buy. But now imagine that we are debating the merits of a proposed change in what we tell our kids about right and wrong. The neurobiologists intervene, explaining that the novel moral code will not compute. We have, they tell us, run up against the hard-wired limits: our neural layout permit us to formulate and commend the proposed change, but makes it impossible for us to adopt it. Surely our reaction to such an intervention would be, "You might be right, but let's try adopting it and see what happens; maybe our brains are a bit more flexible than you think." It is hard to imagine our taking the biologists' word as final on such matters, for that would amount to giving them a veto over utopian moral initiatives.
The humanities and the social sciences have, over the centuries, done a great deal to encourage such initiatives. They have helped us better to distinguish right from wrong. Reading histories, novels, philosophical treatises and ethnographies has helped us to reprogram ourselves --- to update our moral software. Maybe someday biology will do the same. But Hauser has given us little reason to believe that day is near at hand.
I find Rorty's words very relevant to discussions about neuroeconomics as well. No doubt there are exciting developments in this area of inquiry, I think it is important that individuals work in this area, and support research initiatives along these lines, but ultimately I remain of the opinion that with regard to the relevance for understanding social order and public policy, neuroeconomics may lag significantly behind that of classic political economy.
I would suggest to the reader James Buchanan's essay "Natural and Artifactual Man" in What Should Economists Do? for a discussion how the human imagination and volition play off the constraints of nature.
Talk of morals reminds me of a piece that Pete wrote about his great teacher Dr Hans Sennholz who did not hesitate to draw out the moral implications of various kinds of economic policy. http://www.mises.org/journals/qjae/pdf/qjae5_4_3.pdf
Pete wrote in the Conclusion that he was not as comfortable with the moral element in his classes. This is a common and very understandable feeling, for a number of reasons. First up, talk in public about morals has too often focussed narrowly and the speakers have usually been people with narrow minds and rigid, authoritarian attitudes and agendas. On top of that, moral philosophy is a mess so it is hard to get help from that source.
Libertarian/liberals are especially unwilling to hold forth in this area, but there is some literature on the symbiosis of morals and markets, so for some time I have been talking about a sound moral framework alongside the suite of freedoms and the rule of law as the three pillars of policy to deliver peace, freedom and plenty.
This program got a boost when the big Aboriginal reformer Noel Pearson stood up and talked about the need to rediscover conservative mores as an essential part of delivering his people from Third World squalor in the north of Australia. http://catallaxyfiles.com/?p=1280
Speaking on the theme of a staircase of opportunity, he said that the foundation consists of healthy social norms, mores or morals and he noted that people in the mainstream of society where the mores are essentially healthy need to realise what life can turn into when the moral framework has been seriously eroded by the wrong mix of incentives and payments.
As to moral philosophy, this is one of the most hepful statements that I have found.
http://sabhlokcity.blogspot.com/2006/07/condensed-open-society-chapter-5.html
On the role of brain science in helping us with moral decisions, that is a bit like studying the mechanism of a car engine to decide where you want to shop or take your vacation. The more helpful approach is situational anaysis, looking at human action in terms of plans, intentions and decisions made in the context of social situations with various opportunities and constraints. You get better outcomes by adjusting the situation and or the traditions that drive actions. But everyone on this list knows all about that.
Posted by: Rafe | August 29, 2006 at 03:05 AM
Rorty wants to defend “utopian moral initiatives.” That’s quite a distance from the liberal tradition, which takes human nature as it is and vigorously rejects utopian schemes.
For Austrian economics, neuroeconomics is a very exciting and important development. In the past we had two choices: 1) First, there were the pseudo-scientific methods that tried to get along without referring to subjective states. That’s positivism, scientism, physicalism, and behaviorism. 2) Second, there were the all the old traditions that relied on folk psychology and our supposed intuitive ability to understand ourselves correctly. The list of such traditions includes classical political economy, praxeology, and hermeneutics. Now we have a third option.
Neuroeconomics, evolutionary psychology, experimental psychology, and related areas allow us to correct such folk psychologies with disciplined scientific knowledge. We are not self-transparent. Sure, sure, we can’t hope to “reduce” everything to physical language. Hayek showed that to be a logical impossibility. But that does not immunize our intuitive and naïve theory of the mind from scientific correction.
Posted by: Roger | August 30, 2006 at 01:11 PM
On the behaviorists' elimination of subjectivity and mental states, you will recall the story about the two behaviorists who made love and one said to the other at the end of it "You had a good time, but did I"?
Moving on to Rorty, in addition to being very much a man of the left,he is an obscurantist in philosophy as well.
http://www.the-rathouse.com/revmunzpop.html
Some of my favorite psychologists are a bit out of date these days, they are Carl and Charlotte Buhler who worked in Vienna and the US where Charlotte became a leader of the Third Force (Humanistic) movement in psychology. She was interested in the narratives that young people wrote and the life plans that people make.
http://www.the-rathouse.com/Revivalist_winter.html
Another favorite is Ian Suttie who was a major revisionist in psychotherapy. He could have redirected that school in a less reductive and more scientific direction but he died in 1935 with his first book in press.
http://www.the-rathouse.com/Revivalist4/Suttie.html
Posted by: Rafe | August 31, 2006 at 11:59 PM
On Charlotte Buhler "She was continually impressed by humans "self-determination," their drive to fulfill their goals and she came to see this as central to human life."
Rather Austrian? She was born in Berlin but did her best work in Vienna.
Posted by: Rafe | September 01, 2006 at 12:21 AM
Some elements of Karl Buhler's research program
1. The situational model of action, emphasising that the individual is not
passive but participates in the formation of the environment.
2. Actions are oriented in relation to space and time.
3. The inventiveness of the acting individual and creative behaviour.
http://www.the-rathouse.com/Buhler_s_Program.htm
Posted by: Rafe | September 01, 2006 at 12:42 AM